Tuesday, April 9, 2019

Can we use physics to forecast long run global economic growth?


One of the more challenging problems in physics is the evolution of complex systems. Atmospheric scientists study phenomena ranging in scale from those of molecules to the size of the planet, and struggle with integrating the full gamut of interacting forces into a usefully comprehensive whole.

The world’s economy could easily be another example. Individual actions have become intertwined with markets, supply chains, and global trade agreements. Economic forces seem uniquely human, subject to the vagaries of consumer choices and the whims of political and business leaders, almost impossible to predict with any degree of accuracy.

Yet, humanity is undeniably part of the physical universe. An immense body of work in the social sciences demonstrates that - taken in aggregate - we collectively exhibit the same mathematical characteristics seen in many well-established physical phenomena, such as power-laws for our musical compositions, writing, or income distributions, and negative exponentials (or Boltzmann distributions) for the proximity and number in our social circles.

Perhaps, well-established tools from physics can also be used to help address questions about where the economy is headed. Forecasting is well-developed in the geosciences for prediction of such complex phenomena as earthquakes, the wind, and tides. Can similar tools be used to help determine our financial future?

To be sure, this line of thought is not exactly new. Practitioners of a sub-field called econophysics  invoke physical analogs to explain market movements.

My own approach is rather different. Like many physicists, I believe a first approach to any complex problem is to step back as far as possible, to constrain the big picture first before getting bogged down in any details.

Looking at the whole, one technique is to imagine successive degrees or "moments" of complexity that determine current rates of change, each with its own tendency to persist. For example, things stay still - except when they are perturbed by velocity, which is constant - except where it is perturbed by acceleration, which is constant, except where it is perturbed by the jerk, and so on.

Or, consider this beautiful woodcut. We might ask ourselves which way is the boat in the foreground going? Up, down, or staying still? To me, Hokusai conveys the artistic sense that the oarsmen in the foreground are moving upward towards the crest of a wave.

Maybe you see something different. And more scientifically, we cannot know:  all we see is a snapshot in time. Without additional information, assuming the boat stays in roughly the same place would be as safe a guess as any.

This "stationarity" is what we might call "Persistence", or steady-state in the "zeroth" moment. Naturally, we'd hope to do better by going to higher order moments. If we could, we might ask the artist in his grave where the boat was just a few moments earlier. Then we might sensibly suppose that the boat will continue its upward or downward trend.

As a means for making a forecast of the boat’s position, we might call this technique “Persistence in Trends” or steady-state in the first moment. We could feel confident that such a forecast would do better than assuming a model of mere “Persistence” that does not consider that the boats moves at all.

And more sensibly, we know that the boat cannot continue moving up or down indefinitely. To account for this, we would try to go further to the second or even higher moments. For this we might look at other waves for a guide or use a model of the fluid mechanics of an ocean wave to predict how far and fast a wave rises before it falls or breaks.

Economic hindcasts and Skill Scores

My contention is that we can do something similar with long-term predictions of the global economy, by using thermodynamically-based expressions for how economic systems respond to external forces such as resource discovery and depletion to offer robust, physically-constrained economic forecasts.

It can be (has been) argued that it's pretty arrogant - even nuts - to imagine that something so complicated as humanity is predictable. But in its defense, using physics simplifies the economics problem to a level that any theory can at least be tested.

One way to test any prognostic model framework is to perform what in meteorological forecasting is called “hindcasting” : How well can a deterministic model predict present conditions initialized with the conditions observed at some point in the past? Model accuracy is evaluated using a “Skill Score”, which expresses how well the model hindcast reproduces current conditions relative to some Reference Model that requires zero skill.

In the Hokusai woodblock, a zero skill Reference Model of “Persistence” would assume the boat stays still; “Persistence in Trends” would assume the boat continues on its existing trajectory. A model based on the well-established physics of ocean waves would hopefully beat either of these simple models to exhibit “positive skill”.  Then, the Skill Score would be

Skill Score = [1 - (Error of the hindcast)/(Error of the Reference model)]x100%

If a physics-based model of the global economy does no better than the reference at predicting the present, then the Skill Score is zero percent. If it does perfectly, then the Skill Score is 100%.

Hindcasts of civilization growth
I have applied these techniques to evaluate the predictive skill of a new economic growth model for the long-run evolution of civilization. This model approaches the global economy rather like an organism. Civilization's growth rate is determined by its past well-being, environmental predation, whether it eats all its food, and whether it is able to move on to discover new food sources.

For civilization, food is things like oil and iron. We use the energy in oil to incorporate iron into our structure just as people use carbs, protein and fat to turn bread into flesh. Civilization depletes reserves at the same time it uses them, to discover and grow into new reservoirs - provided the remain. Our ability to discover and exploit new reservoirs might easily be impeded by natural disasters, such as those we might experience from climate change.

A model based on these concepts provides deterministic expressions for civilization’s rates of economic growth and energy consumption. Input parameters are the current rate of growth of global energy consumption and wealth  and a rate of technological change that can be derived from, among other things, past observations of inflation and raw material consumption. Output parameters include the rate of return on wealth and primary energy consumption, how fast this rate is growing (or what is termed the “innovation rate”), and the world GDP growth rate (or GWP).


Gray lines: Fully prognostic model hindcasts initialized in 1960 for the global rate of return on wealth, economic innovation rates, and the GWP growth rate. Hindcasts are derived assuming an average rate of technological change of 5.1%/yr (dashed lines) derived from conditions observed in the 1950s. Solid colored lines: Observed decadal running means. The model reproduces observations with skill scores > 90%.

As shown in the figure above, a first principles physics-based model initialized in 1960, based only on observations available in the 1950s, does remarkably well at hindcasting evolution of energy consumption and GDP growth through the present. For example, average rates of energy consumption growth in the past decade would have been forecast to be 2.3 % per year relative to an observed average rate of 2.4 % per year. Relative to a persistence prediction of 1.0% per year observed in the 1950s, the Skill Score is 96%.

Or, using the same model, a physics-based forecast of the world GDP growth rate for 2000 to 2010 based on data from 1950 to 1960 is 2.8% per year compared to the actual observed rate of 2.6% per year. The persistence forecast based on the 1950 to 1960 period is 4.0% per year, so the skill score is 91%.

No other economic model I am aware of is capable of such accuracy, at least not without cheating by tuning the model to data between 1960 and 2010. How is it then that a physics-based economic model does so well at predicting the present based only on conditions 50 years ago?


Well, the obvious answer might be that humanity acts as a physical system and the model at least has the correct physics. But it helps too that the model was initialized in the mid-twentieth century when civilization was responding to an exceptionally strong impulse of fossil fuel discovery. The figure above uses the IHS PEPS data base to show that between 1950 and 1970, remaining global reserves of oil and natural gas doubled because discoveries outpaced depletion. Since, discovery and depletion have been in approximate balance; remaining reserves have been more or less stable.

It is as if civilization suddenly found itself in 1950 at an enormous restaurant buffet. Each time it visited the table it discovered new plates of delicious energy to consume, and its appetite increased apace. At some point around 1970, however, its appetite increased to the point that it discovered new food not much faster than it consumed the food that was already there. The amount of known food on the table stayed stable.

For civilization, uncovering a new energy buffet was far more innovative than merely going back to the table, and it had a correspondingly large and lasting impact on economic growth.

There was a remarkable fossil fuel discovery event between 1950 to 1970 period, and what followed was a clear physical response to this strong prior forcing. Forecasting the future should also be possible, but it will probably be more of a challenge than hindcasting the past 50 years...unless, once again there is a new wave of massive energy reserve discovery, possibly associated with renewables. If discovery once again outpaces growing demand, it might propel civilization to a renewed phase of accelerated innovation and growth. Then, I anticipate that our future trajectory will once gain be amenable to deterministic forecasts using economic equations based on physics.




14 comments:

  1. Are you saying the Garrett Relation is not valid in conditions of energy scarcity?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. The "Garrett Relation" is independent of the time considered (or at least that's the point). Forecasting skill relates to time-dependent physics.

      Delete
    2. Sorry I still do not understand. The Garrett Relation says wealth is proportional to energy consumption. So if we forecast energy consumption will drop then the Garrett Relation predicts wealth will drop. You seem to be saying in this blog that you cannot use the Garrett Relation to make a prediction in times of scarcity. Perhaps I misread your point.

      Delete
    3. The Garrett relation predicts that if energy consumption will drop wealth will drop, but it does not, at least by itself, predict whether or not the drop will happen. However, it does (I argue) lay a foundation for reasonably using prognostic equations based on non-equilibrium thermodynamics to predict the evolution of economic quantities. It's just that the prediction is harder when the past impulse is weaker. Some unknowable future impulse (good or bad) could overwhelm any current tendency for persistence in trends thereby leading to a poor forecast.

      Delete
  2. A few folks hold the view that the flow of oil and net energy into the global economy will soon peak and decline. The assumption is that much of the remaining fossil sunlight will be too “energetically remote” to profitably dig up and process. Of course, many predictions of oil production decline have, so far, been wrong. Or at least, too early.

    Does the Garret Relation offer a prediction for the future of energy production? I was not sure from reading your post. There is plenty of fossil fuel in the ground, claimed as reserves and otherwise. The peakiest say most of it will never be extracted because the energy required to extract the resources will exceed the energy provided.

    We seem to be on the IPCC RCP 8.5 pathway right now. Does the Garret Relation suggest we will stay on that pathway? If the peak oil view is roughly right we will drop off that pathway soon, and have other problems to worry about. Maybe in 40 years looking back, the Garret Relation will describe the full curve of GDP growth/power consumption and decline, based on fossil fuel energy availability and rapid decline?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. To first order, current growth will persist I think. Whatever mechanics of fossil reserve discovery and depletion that manifest current rates of civilization growth have their own inertia. Discovery seems to be a thing we do. I think peak oilers underestimated this aspect of growing systems.

      Of course, reserves, known and unknown, aren't infinite. And climate change will catch up with us. The question is whether we face decline or a crash, and how soon. I think this needs research support.

      Delete
    2. In my observations the main thing that peak oilers underestimated was just how much money the world would throw at declining eroei to mask the effect. As for discoveries most of the shale that is listed in the new discoveries category are not new. They have been known about for more than 50 years but everyone wrote them off as a waste of time and money. If anything they would represent the emergency backup supply in a crises.

      Delete
  3. FIrst of all we will never run out of FFs. Production can continue much longer than the biospheres ability to absorb the waste stream. Production can continue long past the financial constraints which is perhaps the largest element of net energy analysis. FFs have value to humanity way beyond most simple "peak oil" analysis.

    As you can see in the graph the dollar being freed from constraints in the '70s had a profound effect on the economy. More recent monetary/financial activity has really muddied the water even more. Trillions have been pumped into the global economy and is counted as GDP growth as if physical realities no longer applied.

    I am uncertain that any one can model what is happening now let alone predict what might happen in the future.

    ReplyDelete
  4. It would be good to show the Garrett Ratio right up through 2018, and to consider that the fundamental driver, I believe, of the GR is the amazing smarts and desire of humans to make the maximum possible value for their growth, given resources. It's remarkable that in the "sum of all past spending" that spending 1000 years ago counts as much as spending last year. The compounding effect of that past spending overwhelms the fact that virtually nothing from 1000 years ago needs any daily maintenance because it's already turned to dust. I believe ultimate understanding of the GR will rest in understanding Human Nature in aggregate, and the prospects of altering our course will rest in a deeper understanding of Free Will and its limitations. I don't believe we're very far along on this. Heck, economists have only recently begun to appreciate that Homo Economicus isn't obeying Efficient Market Theory like they'd figured.

    ReplyDelete
  5. Spending from 1000 years ago does not count as much as spending in the last year in this model, not by a long shot, due to inflation. It contributes some though, and it does require daily maintenance. More people in the world can understand 2000 year old Roman script and numbers than any other kind, and this understanding requires current brain power

    ReplyDelete
  6. The world was a much smaller place 1000 years ago, however the point is that dollar for dollar there is no "decay" built in to farther past spending vs recent spending in the GR, which is remarkable and perhaps unexpected. I picked 1000 years out of thin air, but the same argument could be made for 50 years ago. Much of what we spent on 50 years ago is just as decayed and land-filled. Inflation makes those past spendings far MORE valuable than their nominal dollar value of course, so the fact that time does not enter the estimation of value except for the unruly inflation term, is still remarkable.

    ReplyDelete
  7. Suppose global central banks did a spectacularly great and honorable job of engineering the money supply so that global inflation remained zero, so that the value of the dollar did not decay with time. Money supply increased exactly to match the true added value of the efforts made by people. Would it then not be more nakedly remarkable that past spending enters the GR with no difference from current spending, dollar for dollar?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies

    1. The GR is independent of decay because it is an instantaneous quantity relating current inflation-adjusted wealth and energy consumption. That's all.

      A decay terms has units of inverse time, and only shows up in the dynamic equations of civilization evolution. Note that current decay is not just on current production (as is often incorrectly assumed) but also on accumulated past production - insofar as it has not thus far decayed.

      Taking this approach, decay and inflation turn out to be related quantities. Looking to the future, rapid decay of previously accumulated infrastructure due to e.g. climate change should be expected to translate to high inflation (and perhaps unemployment too).

      Delete
    2. Yes, agreed on the properties of the decay term. I was using "decay" in the more general sense. The point I'm trying to get across is that to verify the validity of the GR over time, we must be sure that we correct with the proper inflation term. This is where it's dangerous to define a new sense of inflation which does not strictly agree with actual tabulated inflation that you're using to correct nominal GDP to real GDP. The role of central banks in affecting inflation is not a part of the construction of the GR quantitative relationships, and this should be looked at. However elegant your definition of inflation is, if it doesn't agree with real world tabulated inflation, it's going to introduce errors.

      Delete